How
Bad, How Long?
A tentative attempt in
forecasting the crisis depth and duration.
Jacques
SAPIR[1]
The present paper focuses on the possible extent of the current crisis as induced by the global financial turmoil the so-called “Subprime” crash induced. It builds on previous papers, which have been presented in various occurrences since December 2007[2]. This paper is then not to concentrate on the financial crisis dimension but more specifically on impacts on the ‘real’ economic sector.
It will begin by
a review of assumptions and theoretical issues underlying the current crisis
understanding. Recessionary forces in the
0. Assumptions and Theoretical Issues.
So far implications on the ‘real’ economic sector have not been
fully understood. This explains why published forecasts on the recession or
possibly depression in the
0.1.
Assumptions.
Economic disorders are going much farther and deeper than what developed on the US (but also British…) mortgage market. If, from a day to day perspective, unregulated global finance looks as the main culprit, there are good reasons to think that the institutional unbuilding, which led to the financial side of the crisis, has actually been a symptom of a more global disorder.
This assumption, if vindicated, could entail a pivotal re-assessment of the current crisis.
Two explanation main lines are possible. The first one, which so far is predominant, sees the current crisis as the result of limited policy mistakes in the financial regulation field. Regulatory agencies, and to some extent rating agencies too, are then to burden the blame and solutions could be relatively easily implemented. In this scenario we could emerge from the current crisis relatively quickly (by late 2009) and in an economy mostly unchanged, be it at national or international level, but for e revamping of financial regulations.
There is however a second possible explanation line. Finance has been de-regulated because of pressures building up in the ‘real’ sector. Finance had to accommodate to a much deeper disorder resulting from economic and institutional reshaping induced by “Conservative Revolutions” implemented from the 80’s. If so the current crisis is to be understood as the end of not just a given business cycle but a global political cycle. Its extent and duration are then to be much more severe than in the first line of explanation. We would not exit from the crisis without much widespread institutional and policy changes than ones involved by the first line of explanation.
A side effect of the second explanation line would be that the
current crisis is not to be “global” in the common sense but to hit
disproportionately countries whose economic institutions have been more fully
reshaped by “Conservative Revolutions” than others. The current “decoupling” of
Asian but also Russian economies with trends predominating in the
Theoretical issues.
As in every large-scale crisis, several theoretical points have come to the limelight. The huge support the FED gave to private banks raised obviously the issue of a moral hazard situation. This is quite systematic in any financial crash when Central Banks have to play their lenders of last resort act. However, other important theoretical issues have been at stake.
The lack of prudential restraint in lending has not just been the result of the deregulation process, which culminated in the Glass-Steagall Act demise of 1999. Competition among mortgage brokers and more generally speaking among various kinds of financial actors (Banks, Insurance companies, Hedge-Funds) has been instrumental in what can be retrospectively seen as a dereliction of (prudential) duty. This explains how and why mortgage-market special compartments, which were of limited importance in the 90’s became so relevant by 2005/2006. The same can be said about the blossoming of new and highly complex financial derivatives like CDO’s-squared. Their fast development was a direct result of the cut-throat competition among financial actors. Even the IMF, in its Global Financial Stability Report of April 2008, had to acknowledge that:
“…some complex and multilayered products added little economic value to the financial system. Further, they likely exacerbated the depth and duration of the crisis…”[4].
Far to promote efficiency, competition has actually seriously undermined financial stability and led to a string of unsustainable decisions. This is a classical case of adverse selection and raises the issue of how much competition is actually needed in finance. Microeconomics of adverse selection are known for quite long[5], but their macroeconomic impact seems to have been seriously understated. The actual value of competition policies, as promoted in the wake of “Conservative Revolutions” is to be seriously re-assessed. More generally speaking, the paradigm of competition is to be seriously questioned. It is a point Joseph Stiglitz raised in his 2001 Nobel Prize lecture[6], which needs to be forcefully rammed home to many economic policy decision-makers[7]. Highly competitive markets are not necessarily the best coordination tool we need and fostering more competition could be efficiency destructive because no market can be informationally efficient in the real-world economy[8].
Another point frequently raised in reports commissioned on the “Subprime” crisis is the impact of economic context on individuals behaviours. The already quoted IMF report then states:
“…the benign performance of credit markets since the early part of the decade gave investors a false sense of security”[9].
The same report insists on “normal market conditions” as a perquisite of accounting rules[10], and the Financial Accounting Standards 157 itself defines the “fair value” concept as a price a market defines in “orderly conditions”[11]. The IMF now acknowledges that such rules have created “flowed metrics for evaluating the default risk of portfolios”[12], and that the fair value is “compounding market instability”[13].
Albeit belated these acknowledgements are to be welcomed. However one can’t escape the feeling that the IMF, a well-known staunch defender of axiomatic approach in economics when it comes to inflation, has been pushed back to pure empirical “story-telling” as in some institutionnalist works it earlier vilified. Actually both the impact of contextual environments on individuals behaviours and the presence of huge preferences instability under surprise events have been well known for nearly three decades[14]. The impact of “surprise” on market-based expectations has been thoroughly analysed even earlier[15]. The very fact that the traditional theory of rationality, on which mainstream economics are heavily lying, has no actual grounding is now a well-known fact[16]. Implications for economic theory as well as in specific markets have been thoroughly analysed[17], and an alternative view of rationality promoted[18].
The current financial crisis is then raising a two-pronged issue. First, it highlights that major financial institutions are, like the French military establishment in 1939 “a war behind”. They have not integrated into their own theoretical framework progresses made a generation ago. Second, what is clearly needed now is a macroeconomic theory consistent with progresses made in microeconomics.
I.
What extent for
the
Because the crisis originated from the
I.1. The
The
What prevented growth to be even weaker was a spectacular drop of the gross saving rate, which mostly originated from a drop of household saving rates, achieving an historical low of 0.4% of net disposable income in 2007 against 2.4% in 2002.
This period
appears to be quite unusual. Movements of GDP growth and gross savings look
quite related from 1982 to 2002, but the relative post-2002 expansion has not
been followed by a significant rebuilding of the gross saving rate after the
strong post-2001 fall (figure 1). Unusual characteristics of the
Figure 1
Source: BEA - US Dptmnt of Commerce
and IMF, World Economic Outlook,
April 2008.
What sustained too expansion has been the high level of home equity extraction rising real-estate prices allowed. Not only was the housing bubble creating a strong positive wealth effect but, through the mortgage market. Through cashing-out from their houses, US households obtained a yearly average of more than 51 USD billions a year between 2002 and 2007 (with a 80 USD billions pike in 2006) against a yearly average of 5.8 USD billions between 1993 and 2001.
Home equity
extraction, which amounted for 0.4% of Real Personal Consumption Expenditures
between 1993 and 2001 jumped to 2.4% between 2002 and 2007[20].
This imply that every things being equal
the Real PCE got a yearly boost of 2% from home equity extraction between 2002
and 2007 by comparison of what it got during the 1993-2000 expansion period.
This allowed households to maintain high spending rates despite the
above-mentioned lacklustre wage and salary growth. Actually, if we add these
2.0% to the actual wage and salary growth experienced between 2002 and 2007, we
are falling back to the 3.7% real wage growth rate of the 90’s. This however
has implied a fast increase in households indebtedness, as the home equity
extraction was obtained through mortgage roll-overs, reaching previously untold
levels in the
Figure 2
Source: US Bureau of
Economic
It is then possible to speak of a “false growth” to describe the
Table 1
Export Similarity Index with OECD countries. Evolution
1972-2005
|
1972 |
1983 |
1994 |
2005 |
Taiwan |
0,14 |
0,17 |
0,22 |
0,22 |
Hong Kong |
0,11 |
0,13 |
0,17 |
0,15 |
Korea |
0,11 |
0,18 |
0,25 |
0,33 |
Singapore |
0,06 |
0,13 |
0,16 |
0,15 |
China |
0,05 |
0,08 |
0,15 |
0,21 |
India |
0,05 |
0,07 |
0,09 |
0,16 |
Source: P.K. Schott, “The
relative sophistication of Chinese exports”, Economic Policy, n°55, January 2008, pp. 7-40, p. 26.
This pressure has been greater after 2002 than in the 90’s because low income-level countries have begun a technological ladder-climbing process, which has not been followed by a commensurate increase in local wages (table-1).
It is now impossible to defend the idea that the WTO sponsored globalization has had a positive or neutral effect on developed countries macroeconomics.
However, the globalization impact has been compounded with
“Conservative Revolution” effects, including deregulation and curtailing of
social benefits. The upward trend in household indebtedness clearly begins in
the early 80’s. Economic policies known as “Reaganomics” have undermined the
“Conservative Revolution” policies have aimed at reducing the share of wages and salary incomes by comparison to corporate profits and have considerably reduced public spending, which had a high equalizing effect.
Combined to globalization effects, these policies have considerably depressed the Personal Consumption Expenditures potential. This would have reduced growth much earlier but for the switch to credit-backed consumption. However, with income growth constrained, lending progressively has out stripped repayment potential. Household savings fell accordingly in a spectacular way during the 90’s and the beginning of the XXIst Century(Table 2).
Table 2
Average yearly values of personal savings as
Disposable Personal Income % and mortgage debt as personal savings %
|
Personal
savings as DPI % |
Mortgage
debt on non-farm homes as personal savings % |
1970-1979 |
9,6% |
47,6% |
1980-1989 |
9,0% |
58,5% |
1990-1999 |
5,2% |
96,0% |
2000-2007 |
1,5% |
1112,2% |
Source: Bureau of Economic
Analysis, US Dptmt of Commerce, data updated on April 13th, 2008.
What made this evolution possible was the strong “framing effect” an upward “bubble” is generating. When the NASDAQ bubble collapsed in 2000, speculative expectations shifted to the real-estate sector. The rise in real-estate prices then induced a strong “endowment effect”, which progressively made borrowers deaf to any prudential advise. On the lender side, the cut-throat competition environment deregulation has created quickly favoured an adverse selection process. Hence a globally unsustainable process set in from both sides.
There is here no point to try fingering out “irrational” behaviours. If we admit that rationality is always “framed” or context-dependent and that preference reversals are the logical reaction to surprise, then the unsustainable growth of 2002-2007 has been the logical result of rationality. The point missed by mainstream economists is that market-generated “rational” behaviours are not necessarily consistent with mid to long-term stability and growth. Market rationality is consistent with the environment a given market is generating at a given time and no more.
By early 2007
the
The development of the
This is an
important point to understand how bad the recession is to be in the
I.2. Toward a deep and protracted recession?
Three factors are pointing toward a severe and protracted recession. Their cumulative effects are to be felt at the very least till the end of 2009 and probably latter.
First, the wealth effect is now to go downward, for several reasons.
With a brutal drop in house prices, the home equity extraction is to be considerably reduced. If it would go back to its 1993-2000 levels, this would imply a yearly reduction of the real PCE by at least 2% everything being equal. Note here that would stock prices go down during 2nd or 3rd 2008 quarter, the reduction could be greater. This reduction is to extend at very least till end 2009 and probably till summer 2010.
In previous recession, the household saving rate acted as a kind of income buffer. Households reduced their savings to compensate for falling income from various sources. With a 0.4% rate it is clearly obvious that the saving rate is not to play its usual buffer role. As pension funds have been severely hit by the fall in stock prices till end summer 2007, US households are to be under a strong pressure to reconstitute both their wealth and savings. To the contrary of previous recessions, the saving rate is then to increase, becoming then pro-cyclical. Note here that a return to a 2.4% rate as in 2002 would imply a further PCE reduction of 2%.
However, what has been described here is in a way a pure computational approach. What is still not known is to what extent the new context, with the looming threat of mortgage foreclosures and with many family in the neighbourhood expelled from their home, is to impact on US household preferences ranking. One cannot exclude the possibility of households overreacting to the new context and increasing their saving rates to a much larger extent than what is usually forecasted. The effect of the credit constraint now snowballing from the mortgage market to the credit-card and auto-credit markets is also difficult to predict as it could massively change household expectations.
Even if the
Second, if bad news are coming from the wealth effect, the situation in the wage and salary income field is no better.
As unemployment is again on the rise downward pressures on real wages are to be quite strong. As the total number of wage-earners is now diminishing, the global wages and salary income inflow is at best to stagnate and could not compensate for the downward wealth effect. At the very best the real wage and salary income growth could be at 0.5% for 2008 and 2009. Combined to the wealth effect, this could implies a reduction of real Personal Consumption Expenditures by 1.5% to 3.5% a year in the 24 months going from summer 2008 to summer 2010.
To what extent
the fall of internal consumption could be compensated by investments and
exports is difficult to assess.
A low US Dollar
change rate could boost
Figure 3
Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook, April 2008,
Third,
The housing
market crisis and the fall of house prices have already strained local budget
revenues in 22 states and in the
In the same time
the
If we introduce
into the picture growing costs of the War in
In this context economic forecasts have to be bleak. If we take into
account all depressive factors, including their impact on behaviours through
the creation of a highly unstable context, even the IMF forecast, usually
described as particularly bleak, could be seen as unduly optimistic. The
Figure 4
Source: IMF World Economic Outlook, April 2008 and
personal computations.
It is then reasonable to expect that the
II.
Impact on
economies of EU countries.
Forecasting the economic climate among EU countries implies first to
discriminate between Western and
II.1. Western European heterogeneity.
Main Western European countries are not making for an homogeneous
economic group. This is true not just because
One important difference is coming from the fact that some economies
have followed the
Table 3
General savings as GDP percent
|
Germany |
France |
Italy |
Great Britain |
USA |
2000 |
20,07 |
21,20 |
20,16 |
15,39 |
18,04 |
2001 |
19,51 |
21,50 |
20,52 |
15,56 |
16,37 |
2002 |
19,28 |
20,18 |
20,35 |
15,81 |
14,22 |
2003 |
19,29 |
19,71 |
19,37 |
15,72 |
13,31 |
2004 |
21,34 |
19,85 |
19,83 |
15,86 |
13,85 |
2005 |
21,67 |
18,96 |
18,93 |
14,99 |
13,95 |
2006 |
22,81 |
19,26 |
18,59 |
14,10 |
14,15 |
2007 |
23,83 |
20,42 |
19,31 |
13,63 |
13,62 |
Source: IMF World Economic Outlook, April 2008.
In economies where the US pattern is more predominant we find a high household indebtedness ratio (124% of GDP in Spain, 130% in Great Britain and Ireland), a large involvement of the banking sector in credits to the real-estate sector (up to 65% of bank assets in Spain) and consequently a high vulnerability to a mortgage crash similar to the US one.
To a large
extent the British economy looks as exposed as the
Figure 5
US and
Source: IMF Global Financial Stability Report, April
2008,
The situation in
However, as
The real estate sector began its downturn during Fall and Winter 2007. The number of new constructions on a 12 months basis dropped sharply to 375,000 early 2008. Some forecasts are putting this figure to 100,000 by the end of 2008, which would imply to any extent no new constructions during Summer and Fall 2008.
In such a situation, and considering the high debt burden on Spanish households shoulders[26], a consumption crunch is unavoidable. It is to be compounded with a strong reduction in investments, directly linked to the current contraction of the house-building sector. Spanish banks are highly vulnerable to a strong real estate sector downturn. Even if their profit ratios are still good by Spring 2008, they are to suffer a serious shock by next summer.
The Spanish government has already announced an economy rescue plan
and is to inject 8 Euro billions by 2008 and 10 by 2009. This is a step in the
good direction, but is still much too conservative. As the government debt has
been very small in
In such a
situation, the yearly GDP growth is to be more depressed than what is currently
expected. Yearly GDP growth averaged 3.6% in
The situation of
Figure 6
Source : IFO April 2008
Business Survey, seasonally adjusted indexes.
Despite reforms implemented by the Shroeder’s government in 2004 and 2005, which have boosted economic activity, the business climate has been steadily deteriorating since spring 2007. It has been argued that the German industrial structure could shield the economy from the impact of a strong Euro. However, since summer 2007, when the Euro began to appreciate quickly against the US Dollar, business expectations have fallen to a significant extent.
There is currently a strong gap between the assessment of the economic situation (which is still positive) and business expectations. This is particularly true in manufacturing industry. Here the number of survey responses rating the situation as “good” overtakes responses rating the situation as “poor” by 30 points. However, when it comes to expectations, the number of responses rating the future situation as “most unfavourable” overtakes ones rating the future situation as favourable by 9 points.
This huge
discrepancy between situation assessment and expectations is the result of the
sharp drop in future contracts. The current situation is assessed on the basis
of contracts made 6 to 12 months earlier. For the April 2008 IFO survey the
situation assessment reflects the German industry order book as it was late
spring 2007. However, the strong Euro is making German products non competitive
on various markets. The German industry order book is deteriorating fast, which
explains why expectations are gloomy. The very fact that now event the German
Minister of the Economy is protesting against the Euro exchange rate is a clear
signal the situation is deteriorating fast in
As German banks have been quite exposed to the “Subprime” crisis, and with some pension funds already experiencing difficulties, the personal saving rate of an aging population is to increase in forthcomings months. Investments have considerably slowed down in 2002 and 2003 and never completely recovered. Internal demand is then not to be a substitute to dwindling exports.
One can then
expect economic activity to slow down significantly from end Spring 2008 on.
The extent of this process is still difficult to forecast. IMF figures are
particularly bleak for
The French economy has been widely described in the internal
political debate as “stagnating”, which has been a highly unfair judgement.
Actually the French average yearly growth for 2000-2007 has been significantly
higher than in
It is however
true that the French industry vulnerability threshold to the Euro exchange rate
is somewhat lower than the German industry one. The strong Euro is a serious
problem when the EURO/USD change rate reaches 1.25 USD for 1 Euro, when it
seems to be a serious problem in
Another disturbing point is the current government economic policy. Since general elections of June 2007, the new government is implementing a string of structural reforms aiming at increasing the labour-market flexibility and diminishing labour costs. Unfortunately these reforms are to make their impact felt during 2008 and 2009 when the demand is to be already depressed by the crisis in neighbouring economies. Tax breaks included in the French “fiscal package” are much too concentrated on the income upper strata to have an effective impact on consumption. To some extent the policy the new Prime Minister Mr. Fillon is currently advocating is not without similarity by the one Pierre Laval implemented in 1935.
Such a policy is ill-timed and will probably increase the French economy vulnerability during 2008 and 2009. So far, the French government has not showed a willingness similar to the German one to publicly acknowledge how bad the situation is to be. A 1.7% yearly GDP growth target has been maintained. The actual growth nevertheless is to be under 1.5%.
To sum up, Western European countries are to suffer significantly
from the current crisis even if individual countries are to experience very
different situations. The crisis is to be particularly hard in the two
countries where economic reforms inspired by the
Table 4
IMF and alternative estimates for Euro Zone main
countries growth till 2011
|
Germany |
France |
Italy |
Spain |
Netherlands |
Average 2000-2007 |
1,42% |
1,99% |
1,40% |
3,63% |
2,06% |
2008 |
1,4% |
1,4% |
0,3% |
1,8% |
2,1% |
2009 |
1,0% |
1,2% |
0,3% |
1,7% |
1,6% |
2010 |
1,7% |
2,5% |
0,7% |
3,1% |
2,1% |
2011 |
2,0% |
2,6% |
1,0% |
3,6% |
2,2% |
Predicted average 2008-2011 |
1,5% |
1,9% |
0,6% |
2,5% |
2,0% |
Alternative estimates |
|
|
|
|
|
2008 |
1,3% |
1,3% |
0,3% |
1,4% |
na |
2009 |
1,0% |
1,1% |
-0,5% |
0,7% |
na |
2010 |
1,1% |
1,5% |
0,3% |
1,0% |
na |
2011 |
1,5% |
1,8% |
0,7% |
2,2% |
na |
Predicted average 2008-2011 |
1,2% |
1,4% |
0,2% |
1,3% |
na |
Source: IMF estimates published in World
Economic Outlook, April 2008, database
Alternative estimates: result of author’s pooling of forecasts made in
3 French, 1 Swiss, 2 German and 1 Belgium bank, late April 2008.
There is then no doubt the Euro Zone is to face significant economic
hardship in years to come even if the recession is to be less severe than in
the
II.2. Impact of the crisis on Eastern EU economies.
Eastern European countries have known a strong growth from 2000. But
for
An important point to be remembered here is that the OECD export
similarity index increased faster in
Eastern European economies developing along the path of low-cost industrial goods exporters are to suffer an ever greater competition from East-Asian economies if they are not able to make considerable gains both in productivity and production quality in forthcomings years. To some extent the Eastern European economies development path was under fire even before the beginning of the current crisis.
Table 5
GDP growth in EU Eastern economies
|
Bulgaria |
Czech rep. |
Slovakia |
Hungary |
Poland |
Romania |
2003 |
5,0% |
3,6% |
4,2% |
4,2% |
3,9% |
5,2% |
2004 |
6,6% |
4,6% |
5,4% |
4,8% |
5,3% |
8,4% |
2005 |
6,2% |
6,5% |
6,0% |
4,1% |
3,5% |
4,1% |
2006 |
6,1% |
6,4% |
8,3% |
3,9% |
6,1% |
7,7% |
2007 |
6,0% |
5,0% |
8,5% |
2,5% |
6,0% |
6,0% |
Average
2000-2007 |
5,3% |
4,1% |
5,3% |
4,1% |
4,1% |
5,5% |
Source: J-P. Pagé (ed.), Tableau de Bord des
pays d’Europe Centrale et Orientale, various years.
There are no doubts however those Eastern European economies are to be hit hard by the current crisis in forthcomings months. Factors pointing to this direction are numerous.
(i)
If economic activity is to slow
down in the Euro zone and particularly in
(ii) Banks in Eastern European countries are heavily dependent from Western banks, be they European or US. The current credit crunch is then to hit hard the Eastern European banking sector.
(iii) The combination of export reduction and reduced activity is to reduce budget revenues growth during 2008 and 2009. As most Eastern European countries are running high budget deficit and considering the fact local financial markets are to be short of liquidity for a time, an adjustment process on the expenditure side is unavoidable and is to contribute too to economic growth reduction.
(iv) Most eastern European economies have extremely unfavourable energy balances. The rise in oil prices is to have a strong impact both on economic activity and inflation. This would also contribute to further deficit of the trade balance.
Economic growth is then to slow down to a significant extent during 2008 and even more in 2009. This growth recession is to be combined with increased trade deficits and rising inflation. The very positive economic image Eastern European economies benefited from during last years could be quickly overturned, would a significant bank crash or some political troubles happen during coming months.
By any extent,
the FDI flow is to be reduced, raising a serious current account problem. The
combination of the crisis short-term impact and more long-term issues could
have significant changes on the
II.3. European economies through times of crisis: diverse and not
unified?
The current crisis effects on European economies are to be widely
different from one countries group to another. There is nevertheless no doubt
that
Countries whose
economy has come closer to the
The three main
Euro zone economies,
Eastern European economies could experience a brutal downturn
aggravated by a strong framing effect by the end of 2008 and early 2009. The
buoyant growth experienced in those economies was already quite frail before
the crisis outbreak. One central issue could be substituting new markets to the
depressed Euro zone.
To some extent,
the same reasoning applies to some Nordic economies. The Finnish and Swedish
economies are already pulled by the strong Russian growth (and
III.
Conclusion.
The current economic crisis is definitely a major economic event, which is to change to a considerable extent the global economy as we know it. It is to have an impact well over just the financial sphere and it is to unfold with all its consequences during Year 2008 second part and early 2009.
The US but also European economies are to enter a recession, which
is to be both deeper than what is usually though and more protracted. In the
First, the recession
is to be mainly one of “Western” economies. The uncoupling process frequently
alluded about since last winter appears to be substantiated. The crisis impact
on East Asian economies is to be pretty mild. A similar situation is to happen
with
Second, this crisis combines short-term dynamics and long-term ones. It is basically a crisis of the economic model “Conservative Revolutions” have fostered since 1980. It is also a crisis of the economic world order called “Globalization”. This combination of short and long-term dynamics makes an early and fast recovery not a very probable event. Even if the worst of the crisis is to be felt by winter 2008-09 in the US economy, and probably during spring or summer 2009 in Western European economies, the recovery is to be protracted and plagued with high instability at least till long-term crisis factors will not be addressed. We are entering a new economic context, which is to frame economic behaviours and thinking for quite a long time.
In the monetary-financial sphere, two issues are to come to the forefront and are to have a deep impact on possible recovery paths.
The first one is
obviously how deep the US Dollar could fall in coming months, and how long
could it stay at a low level. There is so far a limited consensus among
analysts to expect the Euro to USD exchange rate to stabilise by 1.48 USD to 1
Euro by end 2008. This could be but one is to be aware of factors weighting
down on the USD exchange rate. The
The second issue
concerns Euro future. It is linked to USD fate. Would the exchange rate
stabilise at 1.48 USD for 1.0 Euro, we would be in a “worst case” scenario. At
this level the above-mentioned structural asymmetry between
As any large-scale economic crisis this ones highlights gaps in our understanding of economic events. Even more than during the 1997-1999 crisis mainstream economics, both at theoretical and applied levels, are to be challenged to work out stable and effective solutions. The lag accumulated till two decades between theoretical progresses in microeconomics and macroeconomic policies is reaching a point where some paradigm shifts are plainly necessary.
The crisis duration is also to be determined by the speed of these paradigm shifts and the willingness of public authorities to re-write their agendas and priorities to make them consistent with these paradigm shifts. The longer public authorities, at the national level as well as at the international level, will stay committed to older mainstream economics, the longer the crisis and the highest the probability some catastrophic event could take place.
Exiting the crisis could imply dismantling part of the institutional framework we inherited from “Conservative Revolution”.
[1] Director CEMI-EHESS
research centre,
[2] These
occurrences include presentations made at the Russian-French Seminar
co-organised by CEMI-EHESS and
[3] This is
particularly obvious as far the
[4] IMF, Containing Systemic Risks and Restoring
Financial Soundness, Global Financial Stability Report, April 2008,
Washington DC., p. 54.
[5] J. Riley,
“Informational Equilibrium”, Econometrica,
47/1979, pp. 331-360; M. Rothschild & J. Stiglitz, “Equilibrium in
Competitive Insurance Markets”, in Quarterly
Journal of Economics, vol. 90, 1977, n°3, pp. 629-649.
[6] J.E. Stiglitz,
"Information and the Change in the Paradigm in Economics", in American Economic Review, vol. 92, n°3, June
2002, pp. 460-501, p. 460.
[7] The point has been made in J. Sapir, Quelle
économie pour le XXIè siècle, Odile Jacob, Paris, 2005. See chapter 2, 3
and the conclusion.
[8] S.J. Grossman et
J.E. Stiglitz, "Information and Competitive Systems" in American Economic Review, vol. 66,
n°2/1976, Papers and Proceedings, pp.
246-253, and "On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient
Markets" in American Economic Review,
vol. 70, n°3/1980, pp. 393-408.
[9] IMF, Containing Systemic Risks and Restoring
Financial Soundness, op.cit. p.55.
[10] Idem, p. 58.
[11] Financial
Accounting Standards Board, “FASB Interpretation n°46. Consolidation of
Variable Interest Entities”, FIN 46R,
[12] IMF, Containing Systemic Risks and Restoring
Financial Soundness, op.cit. p.64,
[13] Idem, p. 65.
[14] S. Lichtenstein
et P. Slovic, "Reversals of Preference Between Bids and Choices in
Gambling Decisions" in Journal of
Experimental Psychology, vol. 89/ 1971, pp. 46-55. Idem,
"Response-Induced Reversals of Preference in Gambling and Extended
Replication in
[15] G.L.S. Shackle, Anticipations in Economics,
[16] A. Tversky,
"Rational Theory and Constructive Choice", in K.J. Arrow, E.
Colombatto, M. Perlman et C. Schmidt (edits.), The Rational Foundations of Economic Behaviour, Macmillan et St.
Martin's Press, Basingstoke - New York, 1996, pp. 185-197.
[17] D. Khaneman, J.
Knetsch et R. Thaler, "Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the
Coase Theorem" in Journal of
Political Economy, vol. 98, 1990, pp. 1325-1348. L. Ausubel, "The
Failure of Competition in the Credit-Card Market", in American economic Review, vol. 81, n°1/1991, pp. 50-81.
[18] A. Tversky et R.
Thaler, "Preference Reversals" in Journal
of Economic Perspectives, vol. 4/1990, pp. 201-211. For a more general
assessment, J. Sapir, Quelle économie
pour le XXIè siècle, op.cit., chap. 1, and J. Sapir "Novye podhody
teorii individual'nyh predpotchenij i ee sledstvija" in Ekonomitcheskij Zhurnal, Vol. 9,
n°3/2005, pp. 325-360.
[19] J. Sapir,
“Global Finance in Crisis and Implications for
[20] Data from the
[21] J. Bivens,
“Globalization, American Wages, and Inequality” Economic Policy Institute Working Paper,
[22] The notorious
Jerôme Kerviel scandal at Société Générale is here a good case in the point.
Kerviel’s actions can be seen as a pure example of market-rationality behaviour
in the 2006-2007 context and under internal endowment rules set up by Société
Générale.
[23] Informations
from Center on Budget and Policiy Priorities, “22 states face total budget
shortfall of at least $39 Billion in 2009; 8 others expect Budget problems”, CBPP Policy Brief, by E.C. McNichol and
I.J. Law, April 15th, 2008, Washington DC.
[24] This has already
been advocated by P. Krugman, “Partying Like It’s 1929”, The New York Times, Op-Ed column, March 21st, 2008.
[25] Data from the
Central Bank of
[26] The yearly
reimbursement burden ratio has reached 50% of household disposable income by
early 2008 and is to creep toward 55% during 2008.
[27] German Minister
of the Economy Mr. Michael Glos press release, April 24th, 2008.
[28] See Les Echos, April 25th and 26th,
2008, p. 6.
[29] J-P. Pagé, “Europe Centrale et Orientale: rattrapage et développement sur
fond de crise financière mondiale” in J-P. Pagé (ed.), Tableau de Bord des pays d’Europe Centrale et Orientale 2007,
Etudes du CERI n°141, CERI, Paris, December 2007.
[30] Labour
productivity at the Dacia-Renault Pitesti plant in
[31] P.K. Schott, “The relative sophistication of Chinese exports”, Economic Policy, n°55, January 2008, pp. 7-40, p. 26.